Farms.com Home   Expert Commentary

Impacts of Recent Changes In the Illinois Farmland Assessment Act

Jan 24, 2014

Issued by Bruce Sherrick
Marjorie and Jerry Fruin Professor of Farmland Economics
TIAA-CREF Center for Farmland Research

Department of Agricultural and Consumer Economics
University of Illinois

The Illinois Farmland Assessment statutes were designed with the intent to base property tax assessments of agricultural property on income derived from agricultural use, rather than on market values.  The methods were developed in the early 1980s using best available data and practices for measuring income potential across a wide range of agricultural practices and conditions.  To limit variability through time and across management differences unrelated to income potential of the underlying assets, the income measures were smoothed across time, and subjected to limits in change from year to year of 10% of the previous year's corresponding value.  Importantly, all 50 states use some form of use-value assessment for agricultural land (Anderson, 2012).  The specific approach used in Illinois is generally comparable with approaches used in most other Midwestern states for ag-use valuation, though differences in specific methods do exist from state to state.  However, the principle remains that assessed values are intended to reflect a capitalized value of the income potential that the land represent in agricultural use and not the market value which might reflect expectations of future growth and or conversion potential for example. 

The Economic Development Act of 2013 that went into effect in July of 2013 contains a modification to the language defining the limit to the permitted change in the certified assessed value from one year to the next.   Specifically, the underlined portions of the following text were inserted into the law:

"any increase or decrease in the equalized assessed value per acre by soil  productivity index shall not exceed 10% from the immediate  preceding year's soil productivity index certified  assessed value of the median cropped soil; in tax year 2015 only, that 10% limitation shall be reduced by $5 per acre". (35 ILCS 200/10-115)

Following the enactment of the change in the law, questions have been raised about the impact on farmland assessments and subsequent taxes through time; and what would have been the impact through time if the law had not been changed as well.  The purpose of this post is to provide background on the process used to determine farmland assessments, and to provide additional context to assess the impact of the change on farmland assessments in Illinois.

Farmland Assessment process in steps

The steps involved in calculating the assessed value for farmland are conceptually straightforward, involving the following steps:

1.  Calculate the Gross land return.  The Gross return is comprised of the acre-weighted returns across the major crops grown in Illinois, limited to corn, soybeans, wheat, oats, grain sorghum, and hay; and is calculated for each Productivity Index, or PI point.  The Gross is computed using a rolling five-year average of expected yields, and based on actual producer records for acres and rotations, and uses National Ag Marketing Services records of actual commodity prices.  The income potential is important rather than actual income as it mitigates the impact of good or bad management, or good or bad weather that would not be expected to be reflected in values of income available under typical use, and relies on standardized yield functions for each PI summarizing the typical experience across all parcels.

2.  Calculate the Landreturn by subtracting comparable rolling average non-land costs from Gross, or: 

Landreturn =  Gross - NonLand Costs,

at each point on the PI scale.

3.  The Landreturn is then converted to its implied Agricultural Use Value, or AUV as: 

Landreturn / r = AUV

where r  is the 2032a capitalization rate - the same interest rate required to be used by the IRS in many applications for computing use value.  This approach is consistent with the concept of determining the value of an asset that would generate a permanent income equal to the Landreturn at the given interest rate r.  To illustrate, if you deposited $2,000 into an account paying 5% interest, you could withdraw the income of $100/year forever.  Thus, a $100/year income forever would be equivalent to an earning asset value of $2,000 today.  A farmland parcel generating $100 of Landreturn would have an implied Ag-Use Value of $2,000.

4.  The AUV is converted to a base Equalized Assessed Value (EAV) by dividing by 3 (as is done with residential and other properties as well - a convention that has absolutely no economic effect as the implied tax rates are thus 3 times as high, but is a common convention nonetheless and is used in farmland as well). 

EAV = AUV/3.

5.  The next step is a bit trickier as the Certified EAV is calculated subject to a test for its maximum change from the prior year's value.  This is the only step impacted by the change in the law and in simplest form, the new law creates a common range of change for all points on the PI scale so that changes in income or capitalization values would have a common impact and remain proportional to income. 

Prior to the enactment of the new law, the maximum change was compared to its own prior value and the certified value at a PI point not allowed to deviate from its previous year's value by more than 10% of the previous year's value, notwithstanding the casual interpretation of the limit of a 10% change.  The plain language used to limit the movement to "no more than 10% of the previous certified value" did not contemplate the issue that would arise from applications of 10% to certified values that were nearly zero.  Importantly, percentage changes when applied in the fashion described are not symmetric - a 10 percent reduction followed by a 10 percent increase results in a 1% decline.  This effect was particularly pronounced near the lower end of the PI scale and during a period of time when the definition of "income potential" was particularly impacted by changed in farm programs.   More bluntly, once a certified EAV value was established near zero or a low number, the 10% limitation became unintentionally binding for a series of years.  Conversely, at higher points on the PI scale, as farm incomes increased, the variations allowed by 10% limits on far larger numbers could result in year to year variations that were extreme by historic norms, and didn't really represent a "smoothing" control anymore.  The graphic below shows the resulting channel that developed through time with limitations on annual movements of roughly $1.50/year for low PI soils up to assessment movement of $65/year for higher PI soils.

fig1_final.jpg

The new law simply redefines the limitations on year-to-year change to be a constant at all PI points of approximately $15 (equals 10% of the median certified EAV less $5 as provided in the law for the first year of application) for all points on the PI scale.  After 2015, the one time reduction in the rate no longer applies and the limitation is then tied to the previous year's certified EAV for the median cropped PI soil in the stated of approximately 111 which currently has a certified EAV of $203, and a base EAV of approximately $970.  In other words, the new law establishes a channel of approximately $20 on either side of the certified EAV to limit annual changes. 

In some sense, you can think of the base EAV line as being the "target" if there were no other constraints in the system.  Importantly, it is a scaled version of income and relative EAVs are strictly proportional to income as stated and intended in the law.  Currently, base EAVs range from approximately $590 to $1,220 per acre from PIs of 82 to 130 respectively.  These values represent considerably lower ag-use values than current market values.  It is also important to note that he impact of the discount rate has been tremendous through time - if for example, you consider that a 10% discount rate results in an income multiple of 10 and a 5% rate results in an income multiple of 20, you realize that much of the upward movement is due to the reduction in the rates that have followed the recent past yield curves.  Identical changes in income, capitalization rate, non-land expense or resulting gross each should have identical impacts on EAV regardless of the location on the PI scale.  In other words, one more dollar of income resulting from any change in the inputs would be capitalized into the same change in EAV.  Low PI soils have lower base incomes, and thus are assessed proportionally lower based on the construction of the gross and associated differences in nonland costs. The figure below shows the impact of the changing 2032a rate through time via the implied income multiplier associated with the rate.

fig2_final.jpg

Again, the language in the revised law simply creates a different channel - uniform and defined by the typical case, and more stable through time as well.  It does not change any of the calculations of income, use of the 2032a rate, or any other item that results in the EAV calculation prior to the application of the restriction on the change in the certified value from year to year. 

One important intent of both the old and new law is to reflect similar magnitude changes to any change in income that might accrue to any point of the PI scale through time.  The new language does not - despite some initially reported cases to the contrary - result in the same size change being applied to all points on the curve regardless of the income that parcel has the potential to generate, it only re-establishes a uniform channel to limit annual variations. The intent all along was that the channel restricting the movement from year to year would seldom be binding (not always be binding).  Further, the new language does not change the relationship between income and the tax rate applied after limited assessments are calculated.  That issue seems to be a bit missed in some conversations as well where arguments about the rate are treated as the problem that the change in the law was meant to address - that is not the case, though it should be acknowledged that the tax rates themselves are also sticky and do not respond to changes in assessments proportionally in many cases either.

Source:illinois.edu